Like most European countries, Sweden emerged from the medieval
period on a silver standard. In 1625, however, Sweden monetized copper and
switched to a
bimetallic standard based on copper and silver. As often
happened under bimetallic systems, one metal currency drove out the other metal
currency, and in Sweden’s case copper currency displaced the silver currency in
domestic circulation, putting Sweden on a copper standard. Sweden’s copper
standard remained technically in effect until 1776, but its operational
importance ended in 1745 when Sweden introduced an inconvertible paper
standard.
Sweden turned to a copper standard not because of any perceived commercial
advantage, but because copper mining was an important industry in Sweden, and
the Swedish government sought to increase the demand for copper. Gustavus
Adolphus, king of Sweden from 1611 to 1632, felt that drawing copper into use as
circulating money would reduce the supply of copper in world markets and lead to
an increase in copper prices. Spain, then the foremost power in Europe, had
furnished a recent precedent for the monetization of copper when it debased its
own silver coinage with a copper alloy. Vellon was the name given to
Spain’s debased silver coinage, which in the first half of the seventeenth
century became virtually all copper in content. Spain’s de facto copper standard
supplied the first stimulus to the copper industry, causing the Swedish
government to look to the copper industry, which it controlled, as its main
source of revenue.
Because the purpose of the copper standard was to create a domestic demand
for copper, it would have served no purpose to reduce the copper weight of the
copper coinage relative to face value. Therefore, the copper coins were
full-valued coins, with the face value of the coins close in value to the
bullion value of the copper. Because copper per unit of weight was equal to
about one-one-hundredth the value of silver, copper coins on average had to be
about 100 times the size of silver coins, and the sheer size of the copper coins
seems to have been the major drawback of Sweden’s copper standard. In 1644 the
Swedish government issued probably the heaviest coins in history,
10-daler copper plates weighing over 43 pounds each. In 1720 a Danish
diplomat wrote home somewhat humorously about Sweden’s copper coinage:
A daler is the size of a quarto page … many carry their money around on their backs, others on their heads, and larger sums are pulled on a horsecart. Four riksdaler would be a terrible punishment for me if I had to carry them a hundred steps; may none here become a thief. I shall take one of these dalers back to you unless it is too heavy for me; I am now hiding it under my bed.(Heckscher, 1954)
The transportation of any sizable sum of copper coins required the use of
wagons, and problems associated with the transportation of the tax revenue came
to the attention of the highest councils in Sweden’s government.
The copper standard failed to increase world prices of copper, apparently
because Sweden increased domestic copper production to meet the increased demand
for copper as coinage. Nevertheless, Sweden’s copper standard did lead to
Europe’s first peacetime flirtation with paper money. Copper mines discovered
that it was easier to pay miners in copper bills, representing ownership of
copper, rather that the bulky copper itself. In 1661 Sweden saw its first bank
notes based upon the copper coinage. These bank notes, the first in Europe, were
an immediate success, being much more convenient than the bulky copper coinage.
In 1656 Johan Palmstruch had received royal permission to form a bank and five
years later his bank started issuing bank notes. Paper money experiments,
however, seem to be especially vulnerable to the pitfalls of success.
Palmstruch’s bank overissued bank notes, the public staged a run on the bank,
and the bank failed. The failed bank,
however, was purchased and reorganized as the Riksbank, now the
oldest central bank in Europe.
Despite the fear inspired by the collapse of Sweden’s first note-issuing
bank, in 1745 Sweden suspended its copper standard and issued irredeemable bank
notes. Monetary disorder marked Sweden’s paper-money experiment until 1776 when
Sweden returned to a pure silver standard.
See also:
References:
Heckscher, Eli F. 1954. An Economic History of Sweden.
Samuelsson, Kurt. 1969. From Great Power to Welfare
State.
Weatherford, Jack. 1997. The History of Money.